I. Introduction

Restructuring a region’s electricity sector often leads to the creation of an independent system operator (ISO) of an electric grid, a competitive wholesale market for generation, a regulated market for transmission and distribution (T&D), and a competitive retail market for end-use consumption (Sioshansi, 2013). In the US, an electric grid’s hourly wholesale market price is determined by an ISO’s centralized market operation (Woo et al., 2019). Generation companies (Gencos) compete for sales to wholesale buyers, including local distribution companies and retail service providers (Woo et al., 2019).

A wholesale electricity market’s hourly prices ($/MWh) are highly volatile, with occasionally sharp spikes (Eydeland & Wolyniec, 2003). An important strand of the literature on retail pricing under volatile wholesale market prices is the pass-through of retail prices based on wholesale market price changes. The pass-through is partial, increases with wholesale price volatility, increases with rising retail competition, and declines with customer search costs (Brown, Tsai, et al., 2020; Deller et al., 2021; Fabra & Reguant, 2014; Hartley et al., 2019).

Partially driven by its forward-looking per MWh procurement cost (Brown, Tsai, et al., 2020), an electricity retailer’s fixed price offer (FPO) depends on vertical integration that enables economies of coordination, scale, and scope (Arocena, 2008; Fetz & Filippini, 2010). A substantive research question thus arises: does vertical integration always reduce an electricity retailer’s FPO? Underlying this question’s real-world relevance and policy importance is the ubiquity of fixed price plans (Brown, Tsai, et al., 2020) and mergers of large Gencos and retailers (Brown, Zarnikau, et al., 2020; Brown & Sappington, 2021).

The question’s commonly received answer is “yes,” because vertical integration tends to reduce a retailer’s FPOs (Brown & Sappington, 2021; de Bragança & Daglish, 2017; Mydland, 2020). However, this answer may not hold when residential customers are segmented by consumption size and price sensitivity. As demonstrated below, our answer is based on the profit-maximizing pricing behaviour of a Gentailer (GT) affiliated with a Genco and a non-Gentailer (NGT) unaffiliated with a Genco.

II. A non-Gentailer’s Optimal FPO

Consider a risk-neutral NGT’s FPO of F1($/MWh) for a 12 -month contract period. To meet its contractual obligation, a NGT procures Q1hMWh in hour h(=1,H=8,760) at dayahead market (DAM) price Ph ($/MWh). Mirroring the time sequence of retail market transactions, Q1h is the ex-post MWh amount bought after contract commencement by a NGT customer. However, when making its FPO, a NGT does not know Ph and Q1h and can only set F1 based on its expectation of {Ph} and {Q1h} subsequently realised in the FPO’s contract period.

Suppose a NGT’s average customer’s ex-post linear demand is:

Q1h=αh+β1F1+ωh,

where αh is the time-dependent intercept, β1<0 is Q1h's price response to a $1/MWh change in F1, and ωh is a random disturbance with zero mean and finite variance. The ex-post profit per customer in the contract period is:

π1=h(F1Ph)Q1h.

Let E(Q1h) = μQ1h,E(Ph) = μPh and cov(Ph,Q1h)=ρσPhσQ1h, where ρ= correlation of Ph and Q1h,σPh= standard deviation of Ph, and σQ1h= standard deviation of Q1h. We expect ρ>0 because of the weather’s effects on Ph and Q1h; severe (mild) weather tends to cause high (low) Ph and Q1h. As E(PhQ1h)=E(Ph)E(Q1h)+cov(Ph,Q1h)=μPhμQ1h+ρσPhσQ1h (Mood et al., 1974), a NGT’s expected profit per contracted customer is:

E(π1)=hE[(F1Ph)Q1h]=h[(F1μPh)μQ1hρσPhσQ1h]

with μQ1h/F1=β1<0 based on equation (1), μPh/F1=0 because μPh is the expected value of the hourly DAM price determined by an ISO that assumes the hourly day-ahead aggregate demand is completely price insensitive (Woo, Moore, et al., 2016), and σQ1h/F1=0 under the linear demand assumption.[1]

We assume the probability of a customer contracting with a NGT is J=J(F1,M1,F2, M2 ), where M1= marketing effort of a NGT; F2= FPO of a GT; and M2= marketing effort of a GT. We further assume J decreases with F1 and M2 but increases with M1 and F2. This is because when a NGT lowers F1 and raises M1, it increases the probability of customer signup. However, this probability declines when a GT reduces F2 and raises M2. As the probability for a GT is (1J),J() mirrors the market equilibrium of retailer choices made by residential customers.

The unconditional expected profit of a NGT before contract signing is:

κ1=JE(π1)C1,

where C1 is a NGT’s marketing cost that increases with M1. The first order conditions for F1 > 0 and M1 > 0 that maximize κ1 are:

κ1M1=E(π1)JM1C1M1=0;

κ1F1=JE(π1)F1+E(π1)JF1=0.

Equation (5) states that at maximum κ1, E(π1) ∂J/∂M1 = marginal benefit should equal ∂C1/∂M1 = marginal cost of a NGT’s marketing effort. Hence, when a NGT has a high marginal marketing cost, it employs low marketing effort.

Using equation (3), we determine:

E(π1)F1=h[μQ1h+(F1μPh)(μQ1hF1)]=h[μQ1h+(F1μPh)β1].

Equations (6) and (7) jointly inform a NGT’s optimal FPO

F1=(μQ1β1)+μPΔ1,

where μQ1=ΣhμQ1h/H= average of a NGT’s expected hourly sales per contracted customer; μP=ΣhμPh/H= average of a NGT’s expected hourly per MWh procurement costs; and Δ1=[E(π1)/(JHβ1)]J/F1.

We expect 1≈ 0 because ∂J/∂F1≈ 0, as a $1/MWh (= 0.1 cent per kWh) increase in F1 is unlikely to cause NGT customers to switch and contract with GTs. Hence, equation (8) simplifies to:

F1=(μQ1β1)+μP.

Equation (9) reveals a NGT’s optimal F1 price contains a forward premium of (F1μP) = − (μQ1 /β1) > 0. This premium increases with average consumption size measured by μQ1 but declines with ex-post demand’s price sensitivity measured by β1.

To illustrate F1’s calculation, suppose μQ1 = 0.0014 MWh[2], β1 = -0.0002[3], and μP = $50/MWh[4]. The resulting optimal F1 is $[(0.0014 / 0.0002) + 50] = $57/MWh, closely matching the FPO data (net of T&D charges) available from Texas’s Power to Choose website operated by the Texas Public Utilities Commission (Brown, Tsai, et al., 2020).

The forward premium embodied in F1 is $(57 – 50) = $7/MWh, which is 14% of μP = $50/MWh. Should β1 be -0.0003, the optimal F1 would decline to $[(0.0014 / 0.00003) + 50] = $54.7/MWh. Hence, a NGT’s optimal F1 and forward premium decline when NGT customers consume less or become more price sensitive under smart metering (Jessoe & Rapson, 2014).

III. A Gentailer’s optimal FPO

Consider a risk-neutral GT affiliated with a Genco that uses natural gas as the marginal fuel (Woo, Moore, et al., 2016; Zarnikau et al., 2019, 2020). A GT’s expected hourly per MWh procurement cost in the contract period is E(Xh) = μXh < μPh, where Xh = min(Ph, HR × Gh), where HR = marginal heat rate (MMBtu per MWh) of natural-gas-fired generation and Gh = spot natural gas price ($/MMBtu) in hour h (Woo, Horowitz, et al., 2016). This is because a GT would procure from the wholesale market if the hourly wholesale market price Ph is less than own-generation’s hourly marginal fuel cost of HR × Gh.

A GT’s unconditional expected profit is:

κ2=(1J)E(π2)C2,

where π2 is analogously defined as π1 and C2 is a GT’s cost of marketing effort. Using the same steps for deriving equation (9), a GT’s optimal FPO is:

F2=(μQ2β2)+μX,

where μQ2=ΣhμQ2h/H= average of a GT’s expected hourly sales per contracted customer; β2 = price coefficient of a GT customer’s ex-post linear demand, and μX=ΣhμXh/H= average of a GT’s expected hourly per MWh procurement costs.

To calculate F2, we assume μQ2 = 0.0028 MWh, β2 = -0.0001 and μX = $30/MWh. Sharply different from those used to compute a NGT’s F1, these assumptions are made to demonstrate the combined price effect of customer size, ex-post demand’s price sensitivity, and per MWh procurement cost. The resulting F2 is $[(0.0028 / 0.0001) + 30] = $58/MWh, embodying a forward premium of $28/MWh, that is 93% of μX = $30/MWh. Despite the $20/MWh difference between μP and μX, F2 is $1/MWh higher than F1 = $57/MWh, which is found in the last section. Further, F2’s large forward premium encourages vertical integration observed in Europe and the US (Brown & Sappington, 2021).

IV. FPO Comparison and Market Segmentation

The FPO difference between a NGT and GT is

D=F1F2=A+B,

where A = (μQ2 /β2) - (μQ1 /β1) and B = (μP - μΧ) > 0. Affirming the commonly received answer in Section 1, equation (12) shows D > 0 if A > 0 or B exceeds |A| when A < 0[5].

Equation (12) also shows the necessary condition for D < 0 is

A=(μQ2β2)(μQ1β1)<0,

implying that a GT’s optimal F2 can exceed a NGT’s optimal F1 when GT customers consume more electricity and are less price sensitive than NGT customers. When F1 < F2, it indicates retail market segmentation, with relatively large customers preferring a GT and relatively small customers preferring a NGT.

A plausible explanation for retail market segmentation is that, when selecting a retailer, relatively large customers are more concerned with a retailer’s reputation and financial strength than relatively small customers. Moreover, a NGT likely has a higher marginal marketing cost than a GT that enjoys economies of coordination, scale, and scope. Consequently, a NGT tends to rely more on price competitiveness than a GT to attract customer signups.

V. Conclusion

Our paper suggests that an electricity retailer’s residential FPO contains a large forward premium that encourages vertical integration. However, a GT’s FPO can exceed that of a NGT when GT customers have higher usage and are less price sensitive than NGT customers. Hence, a proposed merger of a big Genco and a big NGT requires close regulatory scrutiny to sustain the retail market’s price competition.


  1. After a small change in F1, the hourly demand’s variance is var(Q1h + β1F1). As β1F1 is non-stochastic, var(Q1h + β1F1) = var(Q1h). Hence, the change in F1 does not affect var(Q1h) = σQ1h2.

  2. The value of 0.0014 MWh = 1.4 kWh = (1,000 kWh ÷ 720 hours per month) matches monthly consumption of ~1,000 kWh per customer.

  3. Implied by β1 = -0.0002, ε = -0.0002 × $100 per MWh ÷ 1 MWh = -0.02 is the own-price elasticity of monthly retail consumption at the total retail price of ~$100/MWh which includes T&D charges. This implied ε matches the short-run elasticity estimates reported by Li et al. (2021).

  4. Changing μP from $50/MWh to $55/MWh or $45/MWh would alter the numerical results below. However, it would not qualitatively affect our answer to the policy question posted in Section I.

  5. For example, if β2 = β1 = -0.0002, then F2 will become $47, lower than the F1 obtained in Section 2.